Pages

Pages

Friday, April 20, 2012

Warren Mosler on Martin Wolf — Part II


Repost: Warren's remarks in bold. Wolf's are indented.

People who reject free lunches are fools: Liquidity trap – part II
Posted by WARREN MOSLER on April 20th, 2012

Fiscal and monetary policy in a liquidity trap – part II
By Martin Wolf

Output is produced by work.

Work is a cost, not a benefit. 

It is in that sense that there is no free lunch.
Might fiscal expansion be a free lunch? This is the question addressed in a thought-provoking paper “Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy”, March 2012, by Brad DeLong and Larry Summers, the most important conclusion of which is obvious, but largely ignored: the impact of fiscal expansion depends on the context. *

In normal times, with resources close to being fully utilised, the multiplier will end up very close to zero; in unusual times, such as the present, it could be large enough and the economic benefits of such expansion significant enough to pay for itself.
‘Paying for itself’ implies there is some real benefit to a lower deficit outcome vs a higher deficit outcome. With the govt deficit equal to the net financial assets of the non govt sectors, ‘Paying for itself’ implies there is a real benefit to the non govt sectors have fewer net financial assets.
In a liquidity trap fiscal retrenchment is penny wise, pound foolish.
I would say it’s penny foolish as well, as it directly reduces net financial assets of the non govt sectors with no economic or financial benefit to either the govt sector or the non govt sectors.
Indeed, relying on monetary policy alone is the foolish policy: if it worked, which it probably will not, it does so largely by expanding stretched private balance sheets even further.
Agreed.
As the authors note: “This paper examines the impact of fiscal policy in the context of a protracted period of high unemployment and output short of potential like that suffered by the United States and many other countries in recent years. We argue that, while the conventional wisdom rejecting discretionary fiscal policy is appropriate in normal times, discretionary fiscal policy where there is room to pursue it has a major role.”

There are three reasons for this.

1. First, the absence of supply constraints means that the multiplier is likely to be large.
Why is a large multiplier beneficial?


A smaller multiplier means the fiscal adjustment can be that much larger.
That is, the tax cuts and/or spending increases (depending on political preference) can be that much larger with smaller multipliers.
It is likely to be made even bigger by the fact that fiscal expansion may well raise expected inflation and so lower the real rate of interest, when the nominal rate is close to zero.
However the ‘real rate of interest’ is defined. Most would think CPI, which means the likes of tobacco taxes move the needle quite a bit.
And with the MMT understanding that the currency itself is in fact a simple public monopoly, and that any monopolist is necessarily ‘price setter’, the ‘real rate of interest’ concept doesn’t have a lot of relevance.

2. Second, even moderate hysteresis effects of such fiscal expansion, via increases in the likely level of future output, have big effects on the future debt burden.
Back to the errant notion of a public sector debt in its currency of issue being a ‘burden’.
3. Finally, today’s ultra-low real interest rates at both the short and long end of the curve, suggest that monetary policy is relatively ineffective, on its own.
Most central bank studies show monetary policy is always relatively ineffective.
The argument is set out in a simple example. “Imagine a demand-constrained economy where the fiscal multiplier is 1.5, and the real interest rate on long-term government debt is 1 per cent. Finally, assume that a $1 increase in GDP increased tax revenues and reduces spending by $0.33. Assume that the government is able to undertake a transitory increase in government spending, and then service the resulting debt in perpetuity, without any impact on risk-premia.

“Then the impact effect of an incremental $1.00 of spending is to raise the debt stock by $0.50. The annual debt service needed on this $0.50 to keep the real debt constant is $0.005. If reducing the size of the current downturn in production by $1.50 avoids a 1 per cent as large fall in future potential output – avoids a fall in future potential output of $0.0015 – then the incremental $1.00 of spending now augments future tax-period revenues by $0.005. And the fiscal expansion is self-financing.”

This is a very powerful result.
Yes, it tells you that the ‘automatic fiscal stabilizers’ must be minded lest the expansion reduce the govt deficit and, by identity, reduce the net financial assets of the non govt sectors to the point of aborting the economic recovery. Which, in fact, is how most expansion cycles end.
For the non govt sectors, net financial assets are the equity that supports the credit structure.
So when a recovery driven by a private sector credit expansion (which is how most are driven), causes tax liabilities to increase and transfer payments to decrease (aka automatic fiscal stabilizers)- reducing the govt deficit and by identity reducing the growth of private sector net financial assets- private sector/non govt leverage increases to the point where it’s unsustainable and it all goes bad again.
It rests on the three features of the present situation: high multipliers; low real interest rates; and the plausibility of hysteresis effects.

A table in the paper (Table 2.2) shows that at anything close to current real interest rates fiscal expansion is certain to pay for itself even with zero multiplier and hysteresis effects: it is a “no-brainer”.
And, if allowed to play out as I just described, the falling govt deficit will also abort the expansion.
Why is this? It is because the long-term real interest rate paid by the government is below even the most pessimistic view of the future growth rate of the economy. As I have argued on previous occasions, the US (and UK) bond markets are screaming: borrow.
The bond markets are screaming ‘the govt. Will never get its act together and cause the conditions for the central bank to raise rates.’
Of course, that is not an argument for infinite borrowing, since that would certainly raise the real interest rate substantially!
Infinite borrowing implies infinite govt spending.

Govt spending is a political decision involving the political choice of the ‘right amount’ of real goods and services to be moved from private to public domain.

Yet, more surprisingly, the expansion would continue to pay for itself even if the real interest rate were to rise far above the prospective growth rate, provided there were significantly positive multiplier and hysteresis effects.
I’d say it this way:

Providing increasing private sector leverage and credit expansion continues to offset declines in govt deficit spending.
Let us take an example: suppose the multiplier were one and the hysteresis effect were 0.1 – that is to say, the permanent loss of output were to be one tenth of the loss of output today. Then the real interest rate at which the government could obtain positive effects on its finances from additional stimulus would be as high as 7.4 per cent.

Thus, state the authors, “in a depressed economy with a moderate multiplier, small hysteresis effects, and interest rates in the historical range, temporary fiscal expansion does not materially affect the overall long-run budget picture.” Investors should not worry about it. Indeed, they should worry far more about the fiscal impact of prolonged recessions.
They shouldn’t worry about the fiscal impact in any case. The public sector deficit/debt is nothing more than the net financial assets of the non govt sectors. And these net financial assets necessarily sit as balances in the central bank, as either clearing balances (reserves) or as balances in securities accounts (treasury securities). And ‘debt management’ is nothing more than the shifting of balances between these accounts.

(and there are no grandchildren involved!)
(and all assuming floating exchange rate policy)

Are such numbers implausible? The answer is: not at all.

Multipliers above one are quite plausible in a depressed economy, though not in normal circumstances. This is particularly true when real interest rates are more likely to fall, than rise, as a result of expansion.
The ‘multipliers’ are nothing more than the flip side of the aggregate ‘savings desires’ of the non govt sectors. And the largest determinant of these savings desires is the degree of credit expansion/leverage.
Similarly, we know that recessions cause long-term economic costs. They lower investment dramatically: in the US, the investment rate fell by about 4 per cent of gross domestic product in the wake of the crisis. Businesses are unwilling to invest, not because of some mystical loss of confidence, but because there is no demand.

Again, we know that high unemployment has a permanent impact on workers, both young and old. The US, in particular, seems to have slipped into European levels of separation from the labour force: that is to say, the unemployment rate is quite low, given the sharp fall in the rate of employment. Workers have given up. This is a social catastrophe in a country in which work is effectively the only form of welfare for people of working age.
Not to mention the lost real output which over the last decade has to be far higher than the total combined real losses from all the wars in history.
Indeed, we can see hysteresis effects at work in the way in which forecasters, including official forecasters, mark down potential output in line with actual output: a self-fulfilling prophecy if ever there was one. This procedure has been particularly marked in the UK, where the Office for Budget Responsibility has more or less eliminated the notion that the UK is in a recession. Yet such effects are not God-given; they are man-chosen. They are the product of fundamentally misguided policies.

This is an important paper. It challenges complacent “do-nothingism” of policymakers, let alone the “austerians” who dominate policy almost everywhere. Policy-makers have allowed a huge financial crisis to impose a permanent blight on economies, with devastating social effects. It makes one wonder why the Obama administration, in which prof Summers was an influential adviser, did not do more, or at least argue for more, as many outsiders argued.

The private sector needs to deleverage.
It’s no coincidence that with a relatively constant trade deficit, private sector net savings, as measured by net financial $ assets, has increased by about the amount of the US budget deficit.

In other words, the $trillion+ federal deficits have added that much to domestic income and savings, thereby reducing private sector leverage.
However, as evidenced by the gaping output gap, for today’s credit conditions, it’s been not nearly enough.

The government can help by holding up the economy. It should do so. People who reject free lunches are fools.

10 comments:

  1. I've read every post on MNE for years, but I think today is the day I give it up. There is simply too much too keep up with anymore. The associated press can only dream of growing as fast as the MMT related press stream. =)

    ReplyDelete
  2. Ryan--- I has been hard to keep up but then I go to other non-MMT sites and see the misinformation. I come back here for sanity.

    ReplyDelete
  3. It is true, Adam. Sometimes I think the the broad world of econ and social sciences has integrated the currency sovereignty concepts into the world view. Inevitably someone like Bernanke will speak or an NPR reporter will file a goofy report and the realization comes back that they don't understand. At all. And the battle for minds rages on.

    ReplyDelete
  4. you guys should send an email to Wolf with Warren's posts, as it looks like Wolf will be following up with an analysis of MMT. I did. And be nice, Wolf is a good guy and should be an ally. Warren does a great job as usual spelling out where MMT differs from the mainstream in a sharp and straight to the point manner.

    ReplyDelete
  5. Hey, you don't have to read everything if you don't have time. I try to pick out things that I think people interested in MMT should at least be aware are available. And I only bring to attention especially significant articles on the major MMT blogs, since I assume that people are already aware of them. I also include posts that I think are important wrt gaining insight into trends.

    ReplyDelete
  6. Yes, Tom, you've been doing really great job here, many thanks!

    ReplyDelete
  7. Tom, You post superb content and excellent analysis; Always on target with all the MMT debates. Its a huge service for those of us that like to keep up with what is going on. Thanks.

    ReplyDelete
  8. Why is a large multiplier beneficial?

    Because it means spending is going to people with a high MPC and is thus addressing inequality which is probably to blame for the output gap in the first place?

    ReplyDelete
  9. Tom -

    The following should be bold as well:

    "I would say it’s penny foolish as well, as it directly reduces net financial assets of the non govt sectors with no economic or financial benefit to either the govt sector or the non govt sectors."

    Thanks!

    ReplyDelete