Showing posts with label economics and evolutionary theory. Show all posts
Showing posts with label economics and evolutionary theory. Show all posts

Saturday, August 25, 2018

Evolving the New Economy: — David Sloan Wilson interviews Tim O'Reilly

Evolutionary theory meets artificial intelligence and the management of algorithms.
Evonomics
Evolving the New Economy: Tim O’Reilly and David Sloan WilsonDavid Sloan Wilson, SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University and Arne Næss Chair in Global Justice and the Environment at the University of Oslo, interviews Tim O'Reilly, founder and CEO of O'Reilly Media

Saturday, January 6, 2018

Jonathan Birch — Organisms as societies


Here, "society" is being used as a metaphor rather than a description. I would prefer to use "system" rather than "society," and to compare biological systems with social systems, since this is more descriptive and less evocative. At the same time, I agree that the use of "society" is legitimate and useful in biology and evolutionary theory.  

There are three major types of systems, corresponding to the three major branches of science — physical, biological, and social. There are resemblances and important differences in these types of system.

That said, the article is short and worth knowing about, since it indicates a rising trend in the field and evolutionary biology is exerting increasing influence on social, political, and economic thinking. 

So is the systems approach. General Systems Theory was founded by biologist Ludwig von Bertalanffy. Economist Kenneth Boulding switched from conventional economics to general systems theory. 

OUPblog
Organisms as societies
Jonathan Birch is an Assistant Professor in the Department of Philosophy, Logic and Scientific Method at the London School of Economics and Political Science, specializing in the philosophy of evolutionary biology

Saturday, December 9, 2017

How Hayek’s Evolutionary Theory Disproves His Politics — David Sloan Wilson interviews Sam Bowles

As an evolutionist critiquing the field of economics, I felt like a disciplinary outsider until I encountered the work of Friedrich Hayek. The Austrian economist was himself critical of Walrasian general equilibrium theory and proposed a radical alternative: Economic systems are a form of distributed intelligence that evolved by cultural group selection. They work without having been designed by anyone.
That was my area of expertise. I had to admire Hayek as a pioneer, especially since group selection was a heresy and the study of human cultural evolution was in its infancy when he wrote. Nevertheless, both topics have advanced by leaps and bounds since then and do not support his view that economic systems work best in the absence of regulations. Instead, cultural group selection theory points to a middle road between laissez faire and centralized planning that is rich with possibilities.
More recently, three distinguished economists—Samuel Bowles, Alan Kirman, and Rajiv Sethi–have made their own assessment in a retrospective titled Friedrich Hayek and the Market Algorithm published in the Journal of Economic Perspectives. 
Evonomics
How Hayek’s Evolutionary Theory Disproves His Politics
David Sloan Wilson interviews Sam Bowles

Wednesday, September 20, 2017

Benjamin Enke — The coevolution of kinship systems, cooperation, and culture

Daily life requires us to cooperate with a large number of – potentially unrelated – people. This column argues that cultural variation in the ways people cooperate with each other are empirically associated with fundamentally different religious beliefs, moral values, emotions of shame and guilt, social norms, and institutions. This suggests that various psychological, biological, and institutional mechanisms co-evolved to support specific social cooperation systems.
Harmonizing personal freedom of choice and action with social responsibility and the self-discipline this entails is a key issue in anthology, sociology, political science, and economics. This problem is fundamentally an ethical one involving norms, in addition to being a behavioral one involving motivation and also a psychological one involving both disposition and learning. Even physically identical twins are not identical in disposition, for example, which results in different preferences and habit structure. Similarly, cultures are diverse and the the result is a diversity of customs and institutions.

Even sub-human forms of life have normative standards even though they are not specifically expressed as norms or values. Since nature doesn't make jumps it is reasonable to infer that ethics develops rationally from pre-rational behaviors, as custom preceded law, for instance. At the human level, culture and institutions are as formative in behavior as choice based on individual preferences. As Aristotle observed, humans are social animals (rather than loners).

This clearly has strong implications for economics, calling into question the assumption  of methodological individualism. While human do makes some economic decisions individually without influence, this is a special case rather than a general one. Making it a general methodological assumption falls under the fallacy of hasty generalization.

The post implies that liberalism and the centrality of individuals it presupposes is not natural biologically, as assumed, but rather it is an artifact of a particular type of society that is a loose kinship society in terms of the post. This would accord with the failure of liberalism to spread widely if it is natural. Rather, many if not most societies are close kinship societies with more rigid structures.

Vox.eu
The coevolution of kinship systems, cooperation, and culture
Benjamin Enke | Assistant Professor of Economics, Harvard University



Sunday, September 3, 2017

David Sloan Wilson and Dag Hessen — How Norway Proves Laissez-faire Economics Is Not Just Wrong, It’s Toxic

A surprisingly simple solution to the conflict between self-interest and mutual benefits at all hierarchical levels.…
The conflict between lower-level selfishness and higher-level welfare pervades the biological world.…
But goodness has its own advantages, especially when those who behave for the good of their groups are able to band together and avoid the depredations of the selfish. Punishment is also a powerful weapon against selfishness, although it is often costly to wield. Every once in a great while, the good manage to decisively suppress selfishness within their ranks. Then something extraordinary happens. The group becomes a higher-level organism.…
Only recently have scientists begun to realize that human evolution represents a similar transition....
In this essay, we have sketched a surprisingly simple solution to the apparent conflict between self-interest and mutual benefits at all hierarchical levels. We are suggesting that the social dynamics that take place naturally and spontaneously in villages can be scaled up to prevent the ethical transgressions that routinely take place at a large scale. Why is such a simple solution not more widely known and discussed? Although we immediately realize this solution when it comes to cell-organism relationships or individuals within villages, we do not realize that the same principles also hold for companies or nations.
One reason is because of an alternative narrative that pretends that the only social responsibility of a company is to maximize its bottom line. Free markets will ensure that society benefits as a result. This narrative makes it seem reasonable to eliminate social controls – precisely the opposite of what needs to be done. Governments have been under the spell of this narrative for nearly 50 years despite a flimsy scientific foundation and ample evidence for its harmful effects. We can break the spell of the old narrative by noting something that will appear utterly obvious in retrospect: The unregulated pursuit of self-interest is cancerous at all scales. To create a global village, we must look to real villages.
Evonomics
How Norway Proves Laissez-faire Economics Is Not Just Wrong, It’s Toxic
David Sloan Wilson, SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University, and Dag Hessen, Professor of Biology at the University of Oslo, Norway

Monday, October 24, 2016

Diane Coyle — Not the smartest animals


Natura non facit saltus. (Nature does not make jumps.)

The current trend in liberalism is to extend rights to animals as in "animal rights. Most liberal jurisdictions have humane laws. Kosher and halal injunctions also relate to prohibition of animal cruelty. Buddhists include all beings. So do so-called primitive peoples.

The idea that reason can be separated from biology and ontology is a Western notion that arose in ancient Greece with the assumption that the rational principle distinguishes humans from non-humans. This was expressed philosophically and theologically through the concept of the human soul. In Christian doctrine, only humans had souls. This gave rise to the René Descartes assuming a separation of mind and body, as well as that animals were machines without souls.

This led to the Western liberal concept of the person as distinct from the individual. While human individuals are unique and unequal "accidentally," human "personhood" makes all humans equal as persons, meaning that there is no innate privilege through birth, so all are equal before the law and all enjoy equal rights as human beings, although under bourgeois liberalism, "all" was initially defined to exclude women and those to of European ethnicity.

This concept and its associated assumptions was questioned by science, which could find no material basis for it. Humans came to be viewed as machines without souls, like other animals. This became the basis for behaviorism in psychology, which was imported into economics as a fundamental assumption called "rationality"as "maximizing utility." Think Pavlov's dogs, Skinner's pigeons and lab rats. This was not lost on marketing & advertising, and PR.

Psychology and the social sciences are moving beyond that view based on discoveries in biology and neurology. Evolutionary theory is also refuting the Cartesian assumptions as well. See, for example, Antonio Damasio, Descartes' Error.

The Enlightened Economist
Not the smartest animals
Diane Coyle | freelance economist and a former advisor to the UK Treasury. She is a member of the UK Competition Commission and is acting Chairman of the BBC Trust, the governing body of the British Broadcasting Corporation

Wednesday, July 13, 2016

Scientists Discover What Economists Haven’t Found: Humans — David S. Wilson interviews Joseph Henrich


Ha ha!
…in our work we’ve tried to test some of the basic predictions made by the Homo economics model using some simple tools from behavioral economics applied across a diverse swath of human societies. Not only do we find that the Homo economicuspredictions fail in every society (24 societies, multiple communities per society), but instructively, we find that it fails in different ways in different societies. Nevertheless, after our paper “In search of Homo economicus” in 2001 in the American Economic Review, we continued to search for him. Eventually, we did find him. He turned out to be a chimpanzee. The canonical predictions of the Homo economicus model have proved remarkably successful in predicting chimpanzee behavior in simple experiments. So, all theoretical work was not wasted, it was just applied to the wrong species.…
In fairness to economists, modeling requires simplification. However, if assumptions are too restrictive, then the models they generate will be too simplistic to yield useful or reliable information. The question in economics is which models are useful and reliable based on quite restrictive assumptions about economic agents.
JH: The central idea that the book follows through is that human cultural learning gives rise to a system of cumulative cultural evolution that, over generations, gradually produces increasingly complex tools, technologies, bodies of know-how, communication systems and institutions. This is effectively a second system of inheritance that has been interacting with our genetic inheritance for over 1 million years. Consequently, understanding humans from an evolutionary perspective requires considering the interaction between these two inheritance systems. The book is built around a series of examples. I use examples of how our anatomy, physiology, and psychology have evolved genetically in response to culturally constructed practices, like fire and cooking, and institutions such as those related to marriage and kinship. 
One central idea that might be of interest to economists is the notion of the collective brain. The process of cumulative cultural evolution that arises from the specifics of how individuals adaptively learn from other members of their social groups means that our ability to produce increasingly complex tools technologies and know-how depend on the size and interconnectedness of a population, over time. This means that innovation, in part, depends on the flow of information among a large population of minds. 
I also make the point that many of our cognitive abilities that we may think of as innate are actually bootstrapped up via cultural evolution from much simpler and less impressive cognitive abilities. Cumulative cultural evolution produces things like numerical systems, spatial reference systems, pulleys, levers, elastically stored energy and complex languages Without these, we’re much less impressive.…
Homo economicus is too restrictive. What to do?
I think the major problem with moving away from the Homo economicus model lay in what to add to the model. The economists I know are nervous about moving away from this canonical model because they worry that it opens the door to the willy-nilly adding of different preferences to fit the data. What the field needs is a disciplined way of theorizing and testing preferences (or irrational beliefs) that can then be added to the model.
This is what I think a fully-fledged evolutionary approach can add to economics — theory that endogenizes beliefs and preferences within a cultural and genetic evolutionary dynamic. Economists can keep all that powerful utility maximizing machinery that they love but it has to be embedded the larger evolutionary framework.
I might add here that Ludwig Wittgenstein's later work showed how language acquisition and use is embedded in world views that provide the logical frameworks for language use by connecting symbols with context through behavior. For instance, pointing is a behavior but the logic of pointing as an indication is logical rather than behavior. This connection is a learned response.

Since this framework and its logic is embedded in language and acquired through learning a language, it goes largely unnoticed and is very difficult to disentangle even when noticed.

Michael Polanyi, the similarly brilliant brother of Karl, author of the The Great Transformation, also called attention to what he called "tacit knowledge" in Personal Knowledge.
The term “tacit knowing” or “tacit knowledge” was first introduced into philosophy by Michael Polanyi in 1958 in his magnum opus Personal Knowledge. He famously summarizes the idea in his later work The Tacit Dimension with the assertion that “we can know more than we can tell.”.[1] He states not only that there is knowledge that cannot be adequately articulated by verbal means, but also that all knowledge is rooted in tacit knowledge in the strong sense of that term.
Tacit knowledge can be defined as skills, ideas and experiences that people have in their minds and are, therefore, difficult to access because it is often not codified and may not necessarily be easily expressed (Chugh, 2015).[2] With tacit knowledge, people are not often aware of the knowledge they possess or how it can be valuable to others. Effective transfer of tacit knowledge generally requires extensive personal contact, regular interaction[3] and trust. This kind of knowledge can only be revealed through practice in a particular context and transmitted through social networks.[4] To some extent it is "captured" when the knowledge holder joins a network or a community of practice.[3]. — Wikipedia
This sort of knowledge is not "natural" in the sense of innate but rather is acquired through experience, specifically socialization, education, and enculturation.

Why is this important? Because the naive assumption is that human minds are mirrors of reality that reflect reality in the same way for all owing to commonly shared physiology. This leads to the incorrect assumption that there natural laws governing the social world in a way similar to the way that "laws of nature" operate in natural science.

Evonomics
Scientists Discover What Economists Haven’t Found: Humans
David S. Wilson, SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University and Arne Næss Chair in Global Justice and the Environment at the University of Oslo interviews Joseph Henrich, Professor, Department of Human Evolutionary Biology, Harvard University

Saturday, May 21, 2016

David Sloan Wilson — Corporate Ecosystems Are Filled with Predators and Parasites

A bedrock assumption of economics is that firms become well adapted by competing against each other. If so, then consider a study that I reported upon earlier, which monitored the survival of 136 firms starting from the time they initiated their public offering on the US Stock Market. Five years later, the survivors—by a wide margin—were the firms that did best by their employees.
If only the fittest firms survive, then doing well by employees would have become the prevailing business practice a long time ago. That hasn’t happened, so something is wrong with the simple idea that best business practices evolve by between-firm selection. That “something” is multilevel selection, which is well known to evolutionary biologists and needs to become better known among economists and the business community.
Multilevel selection theory is based on the fact that competition can take place at all levels of a multi-tier hierarchy of units—not only among firms, but also among individuals and subunits within firms. The practices that evolve (culturally in addition to genetically) by lower-level selection are often cancerous for the welfare of the higher-level unit. By the same token, if selection did operate exclusively at the level of firms, then the outcome would often be cancerous for the multi-firm economy. When it comes to the cancerous effects of lower-level selection, there is no invisible hand to save the day.
The kind of firm selection imagined by economists, along with the invisible hand assumption that lower-level selection is robustly beneficial for the higher-level common good, would be called “naïve group selectionism” by evolutionary biologists. Its biological counterpart was roundly criticized during the 1960’s and has had a half century to mature. Modern multilevel selection theory is not naïve and has much to teach the economics profession and business community.
This is the topic of my interview with Lynn Stout, who knows a thing or two about firms. She is Distinguished Professor of Corporate and Business Law at the Cornell Law School and author of Cultivating Conscience: How Good Laws Make Good People and The Shareholder Value Myth: How Putting Shareholders First Harms Investors, Corporations, and the Public.….
Evonomics
Don’t Be Fooled. Corporate Ecosystems Are Filled with Predators and Parasites
David S. Wilson |SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University and Arne Næss Chair in Global Justice and the Environment at the University of Oslo

Wednesday, April 13, 2016

Lixing Sun — Economics Can Explain the Real World with Two Fixes


Absolute versus relative utility. Why homo sapiens is not homo economicus. Homo economicus, a theoretical construct, is assumed to prefer absolute utility. However, behavioral economicus suggests that homo sapiens actually prefers relative utility. Evolutionary biology explains the reasons.
Apparently, evolution has equipped us with a subconscious long-term perspective that often disagrees with the neoclassical economic assumption that we maximize utility in the here and now.
There is an interesting observation in the post that is also borne out in fact.
The value of reputation can explain such enigmatic human customs as dueling in Europe, “saving face” in East and South Asia, and honor killing in some Muslim communities. For instance, the ancient Chinese practiced filial piety, in which family elders were revered to a degree that they were entitled to the best living conditions—the finest food, the coziest rooms, and the highest social status—even though they were too old to work. The logic: filial piety served as the gold standard for reputation. (How can we trust a person who won’t even treat his parents or grandparents well?) Without knowing the value of reputation, the practice of filial piety makes no economic sense. Clearly, the benefit of reputation warranted the cost of sacrifice.
I was just reading that in China today, filial piety is a factor in one's credit score. Those who don't take care of their parents take a reputational hit.

There is also lifetime payoff versus immediate payoff. Homo economicus assumes immediate payoff, or short term payoff. Homo sapiens recognizes a tradeoff between immediate payoff and lifetime payoff, and has a bias toward lifetime payoff.
Evolution is a blind, amoral process, only caring about organisms that can leave behind the most copies of genes in their lifetimes, regardless of whether they behave selfishly or selflessly in the short term. That is, when the ultimate evolutionary prize is lifetime fitness, being either cooperative or competitive makes no difference, for they are the two sides of the same coin, serving the same end.
Humans have long lifespans and live in stable social groups. These conditions, as biologist Robert Trivers argues, favor cooperation, which often leads to better payoffs than what individuals can accomplish alone in the long run. That’s why prosocial behaviors have thrived in humans. Accordingly, rather than maximizing the utility in every one-shot deal as assumed in rational choice theory, being rational in evolution means behaving in a way that can lead to maximum lifetime payoff.
With the two conceptual modifications—relative and lifetime payoff—in rational choice theory, neoclassical economics can be made compatible with evolution and gain traction in the real world.
Evonomics
Economics Can Explain the Real World with Two Fixes
Lixing Sun | professor of biology at Central Washington University

Monday, March 7, 2016

Christopher Krupenye — Apes Make Irrational Economic Decisions – That Includes You

Because bonobos, chimpanzees, and humans all exhibit framing effects, it is unlikely that this trait evolved independently in each lineage. Instead, it appears that choice biases are evolutionarily ancient. They were probably present in the last common ancestor of bonobos, chimpanzees, and humans, which lived about six million years ago, and may even be much older. That framing effects are shared with several non-human species also suggests that these biases are deeply rooted in our biology, and can arise in the absence of experience with uniquely human monetary markets. Choice biases may have evolved in response to certain challenges in foraging ecology, or they may represent a by-product for selection on other traits, such as emotions.…
Evonomics
Apes Make Irrational Economic Decisions – That Includes You
Christopher Krupenye, PhD candidate in Evolutionary Anthropology, Duke University

Saturday, February 27, 2016

Peter Turchin — Another Victim of Ayn Rand’s Corrosive Objectivism: Sears


The story of the rise and fall of Eddie Lampert.

Cliodynamica — A Blog about the Evolution of Civilizations
Another Victim of Ayn Rand’s Corrosive Objectivism: Sears
Peter Turchin | Professor in the Department of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology at the University of Connecticut, Research Associate in the School of Anthropology, University of Oxford, and Vice-President of the Evolution Institute

Monday, February 22, 2016

David Sloan Wilson — The Libertarian Economist Friedrich Hayek Gets a Makeover


David Sloan Wilson likes Hayek as a pioneer and points out that Hayek did not write the bible of economics. Hayek needs to be updated.

Evonomics
The Libertarian Economist Friedrich Hayek Gets a Makeover
David Sloan Wilson | SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University and Arne Næss Chair in Global Justice and the Environment at the University of Oslo

Friday, January 29, 2016

David Sloan Wilson — My Journey to Economic Mordor, and the Woman Who Saved Us

The more I learned about economics, the more I discovered a landscape that is surpassingly strange. Like the land of Mordor, it is dominated by a single theoretical edifice that arose like a volcano early in the 20th century and still dominates the landscape. The edifice is based upon a conception of human nature that is profoundly false, defying the dictates of common sense, before we even get to the more refined dictates of psychology and evolutionary theory. Yet, efforts to move the theory in the direction of common sense are stubbornly resisted.
There is plenty of dissent among economists, and some of the best are working the hardest for change. The folks who award the Nobel Prize in economics don’t like the edifice that much either, and often add their weight by awarding the prize to the contrarians. Yet, even with all that talent, effort, and the prestige associated with the Nobel Prize, the edifice remains standing in one spot like a volcano adding to its own height and spewing out toxic policies. Why does it resist change? One reason is ideological, as we shall see, but another reason involves path dependence. Neoclassical economics provides an outstanding example of the “you can’t get there from here” principle in academic cultural evolution. It will never move if we try to change it incrementally. It must be replaced wholesale with a more realistic conception of human nature.…
Evonomics
My Journey to Economic Mordor, and the Woman Who Saved Us
David Sloan Wilson | SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University and Arne Næss Chair in Global Justice and the Environment at the University of Oslo

Evonomics — Paul Krugman on Evolution and Economics


WHAT ECONOMISTS CAN LEARN FROM EVOLUTIONARY THEORISTS
A talk given to the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy – Nov. 1996
Paul Krugman

Evonomics
Paul Krugman on Evolution and Economics
Paul Krugman

David Sloan Wilson comments.
After complaining that economic soul searching taking place since 2008 ignores evolutionary theory, I was made aware of Paul Krugman’s 1996 address to the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy. I had read it before but upon refreshing my memory I see that it provides an excellent opportunity to reflect upon changes that have taken place in my own field of evolutionary science during the last two decades.…
In short, all of the components of economic theory that made Krugman regard evolutionary theory as a “sister field” in 1996 require foundational changes in economic theory in 2016.
Updating Paul Krugman, “Evolution Groupie”

Saturday, January 23, 2016

Peter Turchin — Naked Self-Interest is a Recipe for Social Dissolution (a response to Branko Milanovic)


Must-read.

Cliodynamica — A Blog about the Evolution of Civilizations
Naked Self-Interest is a Recipe for Social Dissolution (a response to Branko Milanovic)
Peter Turchin | Professor in the Department of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology at the University of Connecticut; Research Associate in the School of Anthropology, University of Oxford; and Vice-President of the Evolution Institute
ht Yves Smith at Naked Capitalism

See also John Maynard Keynes, The end of laissez-faire (1926)
This essay, which was published as a pamphlet by the Hogarth Press in July 1926, was based on the Sidney Ball Lecture given by Keynes at Oxford in November 1924 and on a lecture given by him at the University of Berlin in June 1926.
Also

Robert Frank: Ruthless self interest is not a good business strategy (a guest post)
Robert H. Frank is the Henrietta Johnson Louis Professor of Management and a Professor of Economics at the Samuel Curtis Johnson Graduate School of Management at Cornell University

Herbert Gintis: Societies whose business leaders have moral integrity are successful societies (a guest blog)
Herbert Gintis, Professor, Santa Fe Institute, Professor, Central European University, Economics,Emeritus Professor, University of Massachusetts, Economics

Branko Milanovic: The Iron Logic of Gordon Gekko (a guest post)
Branko Milanovic, formerly lead economist in the World Bank’s research department and currently is visiting presidential professor at City University of New York Graduate Center and an affiliated senior scholar at the Luxembourg Income Study

Friday, January 22, 2016

David Sloan Wilson — Updating Paul Krugman, "Evolution Groupie"


Excellent comparison of Paul Krugman's summary of conventional economics and David Sloan Wilson's summary of evolutionary theory.

Evonomics
Updating Paul Krugman, "Evolution Groupie"
David Sloan Wilson | SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University and Arne Næss Chair in Global Justice and the Environment at the University of Oslo

See also, Physics Has Einstein, Biology Has Darwin. Economics Has…

Friday, November 6, 2015

David Sloan Wilson — Love Hayek, Love Darwin

It is not an exaggeration to say that as far as his premises are concerned, Hayek is one of the fathers of Evonomics. So is Thorstein Veblen, who titled an 1898 article “Why is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?”
The conclusions that Hayek draws from his premises are another matter. In my humble opinion, they require updating. But there’s no point discussing the conclusions that follow from a set of premises unless the premises are first accepted. Discussions centered on Hayek are therefore discussions centered on economics from an evolutionary perspective.…
A different view of Hayek. To be continued.

Evonomics
Love Hayek, Love Darwin
David Sloan Wilson | Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University and Arne Næss Chair in Global Justice and the Environment at the University of Oslo

See also

Why Darwinian Economics Is so Threatening to Libertarians
George Cooper

What’s the Secret to Joining the “Rich-Country” Club?
Steve Roth

Saturday, October 24, 2015

David S. Wilson and Dag O. Hessen — Bernie Sanders and His Critics Should Know Why Norway Is a Success—An unorthodox approach to understanding economic systems

Senator and presidential candidate Bernie Sanders stated many times that America should emulate the Nordic model in terms of economic policy. Is this so unrealistic, as many critics point out? And what if we took a totally unorthodox approach to examining why Norway appears to be a success story? That is what biologists David Sloan Wilson and Norwegian Dag Hessen do in their essay titled “Blueprint for a Global Village”, which appeared with commentaries in the Evolution Institute’s Social Evolution Forum and is reprinted here. We think that both Bernie and his critics can learn a lot about good governance by approaching it from a multi-level evolutionary perspective.
Evonomics
Bernie Sanders and His Critics Should Know Why Norway Is a Success—An unorthodox approach to understanding economic systems
David Wilson, SUNY Distinguished Professor of Biology and Anthropology at Binghamton University, and Dag Hessen, Professor of Biology at the University of Oslo

See also

This series is a must-read if you haven't yet.

Sunday, May 31, 2015

Econ Journal Watch Volume 12, Issue 2, May 2015


Econ Journal Watch
Volume 12, Issue 2, May 2015

In this issue (.pdf):
Evolution, moral sentiments, and the welfare state: Many now maintain that multilevel selection created a sympathetic species with yearnings for social solidarity. Several evolutionary authors on the political left suggest that collectivist politics is an appropriate way to meet that yearning. Harrison Searles agrees on evolution and human nature, but faults them for neglecting Hayek’s charge of atavism: The modern polity and the ancestral band are worlds apart, rendering collectivist politics inappropriate and misguided. David Sloan Wilson, Robert Kadar, and Steve Roth respond, suggesting that new evolutionary paradigms promise to transcend old ideological categories.
More articles but this looks most interesting to me.

ht Tyler Cowen at Marginal Revolution