Showing posts with label open economy. Show all posts
Showing posts with label open economy. Show all posts

Sunday, October 15, 2017

Peter Cooper — Open Economy Considerations: The Balance of Payments

One suggestion in the comments to the ongoing “short & simple” series is to cover the balance of payments. This will be covered at some point in the introductory series, but I am still considering how best to present it in brief, simple form. With that in mind, it seemed worth attempting a regular post on the topic. The post is still intended to be elementary in nature, but is perhaps at about the introductory university level. The post is also too long to qualify as “short”, even allowing for the fact that some recent parts of the series have already stretched the definition of “short” beyond what I would have preferred.
heteconomist
Open Economy Considerations: The Balance of Payments
Peter Cooper

Sunday, September 3, 2017

China's Xi says BRICS must promote open world economy

The BRICS group of emerging economies must promote trade liberalization and an open world economy, Chinese President Xi Jinping said at a business meeting on Sunday at the start of a three-day summit being held in southeastern China.

The heads of state from Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa will gather in the city of Xiamen through Tuesday, giving China as host its latest chance to position itself as a bulwark of globalization in the face of U.S. President Donald Trump’s “America First” agenda.
How the worm turns (and ideology changes) in the face of interests.
Reuters
China's Xi says BRICS must promote open world economy
Yawen Chen and Michael Martina

Monday, February 8, 2016

Bill Mitchell — The capacity of the state and the open economy – Part 1

Wolfgang Merkel wrote in his recent Op Ed (February 5, 2016) – Economy, Culture And Discourse: Social Democracy In A Cosmopolitanism Trap? – that “we are dealing with a partially deliberate, partially careless surrender of the state’s capacity to regulate and intervene in an economy that structurally creates socio-economic inequality and erodes the fundamental democratic principle of political equality”. I highlight, the “partially deliberate, partially careless surrender” description of what has occurred over the last several decades as neo-liberalism has gained traction. Today’s blog continues my series that will form the content for my next book (due out later this year) about the impacts of globalisation on the capacities of the nation state. Our contention (I am writing this with Italian journalist and author Thomas Fazi) is that there has been no diminuition in the power of the state to impact on the domestic economy. The neo-liberal era has seen many commentators deny that proposition, yet, knowingly advocate use of these powers to further advantage capital at the expense of labour. The state is still central to the picture – it just helps capital more and workers less than it did during the full employment period in the Post World War II decades.…
Bill Mitchell – billy blog
The capacity of the state and the open economy – Part 1
Bill Mitchell | Professor in Economics and Director of the Centre of Full Employment and Equity (CofFEE), at University of Newcastle, NSW, Australia

Tuesday, April 7, 2015

Ramanan — Interest Rate, Growth And Debt Sustainability

John Maynard Keynes’ biggest disservice to the profession is to not start with the open economy.
Of course, this is not only due to Keynes, although as the founder of macroeconomics, he can be claimed that he started it. Most macroeconomists still begin with focus on the nation since macro is based on national accounts.

I have been saying for some time, along with Ramanan and others, that economists need to start focusing chiefly on the global economy as a closed economy, that is, a complex system with entangled webs of elements and relationships in overlapping groups, and a vast network with many nodes. Nation state play an important part in this, of course, and since the time of Keynes, so do international institutions developed subsequently. In addition, owing to advances in communications and transportation technology, the world is "shrinking" and becoming more integrated, with interdependence rising. The combined role of the social, political and economic is also being increasingly recognized as institutions play a greater part, with the result that those who control these institutions set the institutional arrangements that become socially, politically and economically influential if not determinative.

The balance of payment issues to which Ramanan has been pointing for some time is just one of many issues and issue types that need to be taken in account, just in economics. There are many others, as we are becoming woefully aware through the advent of climate change and the threat of pandemics, for instance.

The closest thing to a comprehensive view that I can think of historically is Bucky Fuller's World Game (I've adjusted the paragraphing for easier reading here).
In the 1960's Buckminster Fuller proposed a “great logistics game” and “world peace game” (later shortened to simply, the “World Game”) that was intended to be a tool that would facilitate a comprehensive, anticipatory, design science approach to the problems of the world. The use of “world” in the title obviously refers to Fuller's global perspective and his contention that we now need a systems approach that deals with the world as a whole, and not a piece meal approach that tackles our problems in what he called a “local focus hocus pocus” manner.
The entire world is now the relevant unit of analysis, not the city, state or nation. For this reason, World Game programming generally used Fuller's Dymaxion Map for the plotting of resources, trends, and scenarios essential for playing. We are, in Fuller's words, onboard Spaceship Earth, and the illogic of 200 nation state admirals all trying to steer the spaceship in different directions is made clear through the metaphor - as well in Fuller's more caustic assessment of nation states as “blood clots” in the world's global metabolism.
The logic for the use of the word “game” in the title is even more instructive. It says a lot about Fuller's approach to governance and social problem solving. Obviously intended as a very serious tool, Fuller choose to call his vision a “game” because he wanted it seen as something that was accessible to everyone, not just the elite few in the power structure who thought they were running the show. In this sense, it was one of Fuller's more profoundly subversive visions.
Fuller wanted a tool that would be accessible to everyone, whose findings would be widely disseminated to the masses through a free press, and which would, through this ground-swell of public vetting and acceptance of solutions to society's problems, ultimately force the political process to move in the direction that the values, imagination and problem solving skills of those playing the democratically open world game dictated. It was a view of the political process that some might think naive, if they only saw the world for what it was when Fuller was proposing his idea (the 1960s) - minus personal computers and the Internet.
The playing field was not to be so much as leveled, or expanded, but the good 'ol boy political process was to subverted out of existence by a process that brings Thomas Jefferson into the twentieth century. In order to have this kind of power, the game needed to have the kind of information and tools for manipulating that information that empowers. It needed a comprehensive database that would provide the players of the world game with better data than their politically elected or appointed counterparts.
They needed an inventory of the world's vital statistics--where everything was and in what quantities and qualities, from minerals to manufactured goods and services, to humans and their unmet needs as well as capabilities. They also needed an information source that monitored the current state of the world, bringing vital news into the “game room” live.
None of this existed when Fuller began talking about a world game. And then something funny happened on the way to the twenty-first century: CNN, personal computers, CD ROMS, the Internet and worldwide web, supercomputer power on personal computers and reams of data about the world, its resources, problems and potential solutions started to bubble to the surface and transform the world and the way we communicate, do business, research and govern.
The World Game that Fuller envisioned was to be a place where individuals or teams of people came and competed, or cooperated, to:
Make the world work, for 100% of humanity, in the shortest possible time, through spontaneous cooperation, without ecological offense or the disadvantage of anyone.
Economist Kenneth Boulding proposed something similar as his emphasis shifted from focus on economics to general systems theory, of which he was a co-founder. The title of his book, The World as a Total System, is indicative of this, but as a committed Quaker, Boulding was, like Fuller, committed to world peace and distributed prosperity as an end-in-view. Another of his books is Human Betterment, for example. Conflict resolution was also high on his list. He was under no utopian illusions. But he believed that humans hold their destiny in their hands collectively as a species, if they would take ahold of it.

Foundationally, the quest comes back to the enduring question of ethics and social & political philosophy that was first proposed in the West by the Ancient Greeks — What is a good life in a good society? In order to deal with this comprehensively in an integrated fashion, all disciplines need to be brought to bear in a open and ongoing debate over the future of humanity as a species.

There's a saying, "Don't sweat the small stuff." But that does not mean that apparently small stuff can be overlooked. As Aquinas said at the outset of De ente et essentia, paraphrasing Aristotle, "A small mistake in the beginning is a big one in the end, according to the Philosopher in the first book of On the Heavens and the Earth."

The Case For Concerted Action
Interest Rate, Growth And Debt Sustainability
Ramanan

Friday, October 25, 2013

Bill Mitchell — External economy considerations – Part 5

I am now using Friday’s blog space to provide draft versions of the Modern Monetary Theory textbook that I am writing with my colleague and friend Randy Wray. We expect to publish the text sometime in 2013. Our (very incomplete) textbook home page – Modern Monetary Theory and Practice – has draft chapters and contents etc in varying states of completion. Comments are always welcome. Note also that the text I post here is not intended to be a blog-style narrative but constitutes the drafting work I am doing – that is, the material posted will not represent the complete text. Further it will change as the drafting process evolves.

Chapter 21 Policy in an Open Economy: Exchange Rates, Balance of Payments, and Competitiveness
This material updates the work already done on Chapter 21 that appeared in the following blogs:
The earlier draft had some gaps and some sections to complete which is what I am doing today. The sections I am working on today are not in any particular sequential order.
21.6 The relationship between the Current Account and the Capital Account of the Balance of Payments
Bill Mitchell – billy blog
William F. (Bill) Mitchell | Professor of Economics at Charles Darwin University, Professor of Economics at the University of Newcastle, and inaugural director of CofFEE